The Income Tax: The Decision of the Supreme Court

THE INCOME TAX.

1.—THE DECISION OF THE SUPREME COURT.

By THE HON. GEORGE S. BOUTWELL,
EX-SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY.

 

THE recent contest before the Supreme Court of the United States, which involved the validity of so much of the Tariff Act of 1894 as imposed a tax on incomes, was only less important than the contests before that Court involving the right of secession and the constitutionality of the measures of reconstruction.

The importance of the controversy did not depend upon the questions arising from the peculiarities of the law of 1894, but upon the question of the validity of any income tax, and more particularly upon the validity of so much of the act as provided for a levy of a tax upon rent of land or income from real estate.

Upon one point, there was agreement at the bar, viz.: That, by the Constitution, Federal taxes are divided into two classes; those which are direct taxes on the one hand, and those which are either duties, imposts or excises on the other.

Capitation taxes, and taxes on land, are held to be direct taxes, and on this point there was no difference of opinion. Nor can there be any doubt that, under the Constitution, direct taxes must be apportioned among the States according to the number of inhabitants in each State.

It was held by the Court, six of the eight judges concurring in the opinion, that taxes on the rent of land or the income from real estate are, in fact, taxes upon the real estate itself, and upon the theory that the rent or income from real estate is an incident of the ownership of the estate. As a result of this opinion, so much of the act of 1894 as provided for the levy of a tax on the income from land, is declared to be unconstitutional and void.

The Court was also of opinion that the income from bonds of States and municipalities was not subject to taxation by the national government. Consequently, so much of the act of 1894 as provided for a levy of taxes upon incomes from the bonds of States and municipalities was declared to be invalid.

Upon three other questions of importance the Court was equally divided, and therefore no opinion was expressed.

(1.) Whether the void provisions as to the income from real estate invalidated the whole act? (2.) Whether as to the income from personal property, as such, the act is unconstitutional, as a levy of direct taxes? (3.) Whether any part of the tax, if not considered as a direct tax, is invalid for want of uniformity on either of the grounds suggested in the argument?

The exemption from taxation of the income from State and municipal bonds was sustained by the whole Court, and is in accordance with the decisions of the Supreme Court from an early period in its history.

In a public point of view, the validity of the existing tax act, in so far as its validity depends upon the peculiarity of its provisions, is of no considerable importance, but the exemption from taxation of the rent and income from real estate, except the levy is through the rule of apportionment and among the States, works, practically, a very serious impairment of the ability of the government to raise revenue. It may well be assumed, as was suggested in the opinion of the Court, that an income tax and direct taxes through the States should be resorted to only in an exigency, but it is of supreme importance that the government should be able, in an exigency, to raise revenue from rents and incomes from real estate by some practicable method.

In every government the power of taxation is an essential condition of continuing existence, and every limitation upon the exercise of that power is a limitation of the capacity of the government to exist.

By the Articles of Confederation the general government had no power to levy taxes, and yet it had power to incur debts. At the end of ten years its insolvency was apparent, and its incapacity, as a government, had been demonstrated to the thoughtful men of the country. The downfall of the Confederation was due to its inability to levy taxes; and the Constitution of the United States had its rise in that experience. With the power to levy taxes, even with all its other infirmities on its head, the Confederation might have outlasted, and it is probable that it would have outlasted, the eighteenth century.

It was in the presence of that condition of public affairs that the Constitution of the United States was created; and, within the range of probabilities, nothing can be more reasonable than the supposition that the framers of that instrument intended to avoid the error which had caused the wreck of the confederate government.

If this be so, then it may be inferred fairly, that when the Convention gave to Congress power "to lay and collect taxes, duties, imposts and excises," the Convention intended to set forth, as well, the limitations to the exercise of the power, to define the method of its exercise, and, finally, that, in these particulars, nothing was to be left for inference, conjecture or argument.

Except for the presence of limiting and qualifying clauses in the Constitution, the phrase quoted gave to Congress power to levy taxes upon all the persons and property of the nation, and wherever resident, or situated, and with an authority equivalent to that which might be exercised by a State over the persons and property within its jurisdiction.

Beyond this, and exclusive of the power of the States, the right to levy customs duties was vested exclusively in the general government. This concession by the States was not made without debate, nor without hesitation, especially by Rhode Island, but the concession was not procured through any compromise. It is suggested in the opinion of the Court that there were inland States, and that those States, in consideration of the concession by the maritime States of the right to levy customs duties, agreed to a system of direct taxation upon the basis of population, and that it was foreseen that under that system a disproportionate burden would fall upon the inland States. The truth is that every one of the thirteen States was a maritime State; all were engaged in commerce; all alike, if not equally, were interested in the collection of customs duties by States, and they were alike, if not equally, interested in transferring the power to the national government. There was in the Convention, at the end, a general agreement upon two points, namely: that there was manifest injustice in allowing the duties to pass into the treasury of the State in which the port of entry might be situated; and that conflicting tariff systems would be injurious to regular commerce, and to the growth of manufactures.

In the second clause of the tenth section of the first article of the Constitution, the words "imposts or duties" are limited to taxes on "imports or exports," and hence it is not within the competency of the States to levy "imposts or duties," except for the use of the treasury of the United States as is stipulated in the said clause.

The taxes, known as "imposts" and "duties," having thus passed by the provisions of the Constitution from the States to the United States, all other taxes which the government can levy fall under the head of "taxes" or "excises."

There is a large sense and a not uncommon usage, which give to the word "taxes" a definition whose scope includes duties, imposts and excises, but in the Constitution the word is so limited and controlled that "excises," as well as "duties" and "imposts," are not within the meaning of the word "taxes." In the extract from the Constitution, already quoted, "taxes" and "excises" are spoken of as distinct means of raising a revenue for the specified purposes of the government.

By the third clause of section two, article one, "direct taxes" were to be apportioned among the several States, "according to their respective numbers;" and by the fourth clause of section nine of the same article, it is declared that "no capitation, or other direct, tax shall be laid, unless in proportion to the census or enumeration herein before directed to be taken."

Thus are these two provisions of the Constitution connected together and thus does it appear that the words "tax" and "taxes," and the phrase "no capitation, or other, direct tax," were designed by the framers of the Constitution to include only those "direct taxes" which were neither "excise levies" nor "duties," nor "imposts." Every tax upon a man or a thing is a direct tax, and in this large and every-day meaning of the phrase, it follows that capitation taxes, land taxes, excises, duties and imposts are one and all "direct taxes." No one, however, whether advocate or public writer, has ever contended for this construction of the Constitution.

Again, a land tax has always been classed as a "direct tax." The same statement is applicable to a capitation tax. Indeed, a capitation tax is declared in the Constitution to be a direct tax. It is worthy of notice that in the fourth clause of section nine of article one, the word "tax" is used in the singular,— "no capitation, or other direct, tax shall be laid, unless in proportion to the census or enumeration herein before directed to be taken," thus giving a basis for the argument that two subjects, and two only, were marked for direct taxation, and brought within the scope of the third clause of section two of article one.

These two taxes, by long usage and universal consent, are "direct" taxes, and they have no quality or peculiarity which justifies their classification under any other head. By a broad definition taxes on carriages, on watches, on incomes, on professions, on produce, as tobacco and cotton, the "imposts and duties" levied on goods imported, are, one and all, "direct taxes," but one and all they are naturally and properly subject to other classifications.

In every case thus enumerated, and in every other case that might be added to the enumeration, the tax acts will aim and must aim at the thing to be taxed and at the possessor of the thing to be taxed. Thus are they all "direct taxes "; but they are all something else, and they are all to be taxed under other classifications, or they must fall in with capitation and land taxes, and thus would the government be forced to rely upon customs duties and levies upon the States.

Thus indirectly would the old Confederation be revived, and thus a government that had withstood the assaults of war might be disintegrated by processes of law in time of peace.

Of all the objects of taxation an income tax is an "excise tax," practically, etymologically, and without a rival. As to all other objects of taxation, the "excise" can only be secured in form to be useful as public revenue, by a process of conversion; while an income may be divided and the "excise," or the part cut out, can be used as revenue without change of fact or form.

Further, if this analysis be accepted, it follows that the phrase "excise taxes," as used in the Constitution, must include every form of taxes which are not "imposts and duties" on the one side, or "direct taxes" on the other; and if the phrase "direct taxes" is held to include any tax other than a land tax and a capitation tax, then there will remain no subject of taxation to which the phrase "excise tax" can be referred.

To assume that any one of the proper objects of taxation which may be found between a capitation tax and a land tax on the one side, and "customs imposts and duties" on the other, was to be taxed in conformity to the third clause of section two, article one, is to assume that the authors of the Constitution were incapable, not merely of framing a government, but of providing for its continued existence. Is it conceivable that taxes on incomes, on professional service, on carriages, on silver-ware and gold-ware, on cotton, on tobacco, can be levied upon the States in proportion to population and collection thereof be made ?

And if not, can we assume that the men who made the Constitution anticipated that the experiment would ever be tried?

And if the experiment was not to be tried, did they intend to limit taxation to lands, to heads, and to customs duties?

They made a contrary declaration when they gave to Congress unlimited power to levy taxes. The power remains. A reasonable way for its exercise must be found.

Is it too much to say that this proposition is absurd, viz. that a tax on a carriage and the owner of a carriage is an excise tax and may be assessed directly and personally, and that a tax upon the receiver of an income in money is a "direct tax," and can only be assessed upon the States, and that without any inquiry as to the existence of persons in the enjoyment of incomes?

The last branch of this proposition was asserted by Mr. Edmunds (Argument, pp. 16, 17), and he assumed that the first branch of the proposition was already the law of the land (p. 12).

The Levy and collection of an income tax through the States, and upon the basis of population, would be an impossibility, on account of the manifest injustice of the proceeding. Mr. Edmunds' proposition was, in substance, a declaration that the possessors of incomes, however derived, and whatever the public exigencies, should be relieved of all liability to contribute to the public revenues. To say that an income tax of fifty million dollars may be assessed upon the States in proportion to population, is to declare, in effect, that it shall not be collected by any process; inasmuch as no just man or equitable court could say that it ought to be paid.

When Mr. Choate approached the conclusion of the argument, aimed at the existence of a power in Congress to levy an income tax, and not merely an argument against the constitutionality of the statute of 1894, he shrank from a full indorsement of the position that had been taken by his two associates.

He qualified the claim, but the new position seemed to be equally at variance with the opinions of the Court in the Hylton case and the Springer case. He precipitated a theory upon the Court, which for a hundred years had lain dormant in the Constitution of the country,—a theory of which neither Marshall nor Story had had knowledge. That the theory, in its main feature, was accepted by the Court, is a marked tribute to Mr. Choate's quality as an advocate.

With the approval of his associates he thus states his new position—a change of front in the face of the enemy. "Therefore, for the purposes of this argument, I shall assume what my adversaries claim. I shall assume that it may possibly be decided by this court, as it has so often been decided before, that all duties, all excises, all imposts, are shut out from the class of direct taxes by the necessary meaning and effect of the Constitution, and that they are to be administered by the rule of uniformity, as they ought to be in this law and are not. I shall claim, upon the other hand, that at any rate, so far as regards the direct, inevitable, necessary income, and outgrowth of real estate and personal estate, the tax is a direct tax levied upon the proper subject of a direct tax within the meaning of the Constitution, and is therefore invalid." (Argument, p. 11.)

Thus leaving to the Court the general proposition "that all duties, all excises, all imposts fall under the rule of uniformity and not under the rule of apportionment among the States," he excepts incomes which are "the outgrowth of real estate and personal estate" from classification as "duties, excises, or imposts," and claims that they are direct taxes, and that they can only be levied upon the States and according to population. So much of this claim as relates to the outgrowth of real estate was accepted by the Court.

In practice the distinction would seem to be this: A citizen who owns a carriage, or raises cotton or tobacco, or who follows a business that yields a profit, or pursues a profession from which some gains are derived, may be compelled personally to pay a tax on the thing owned, or on the article produced, or on the income earned, and upon the theory that these levies fall under the head of "excise taxes" while the rent of lands and houses and stores, and the earnings of moneys invested in bonds, stocks and securities of every sort, can only be reached through the apportionment system, by which the new, frontier, and not yet wealthy State of Nebraska, as an example, would be assessed three times the amount that would be levied upon the State of Rhode Island, where wealth has been accumulating in families and in institutions for more than two and a half centuries.

Again, as a system of taxation, as a practical scheme for raising a revenue, who does not foresee that never, never in the centuries, will the poorer States consent to a levy of an income tax of fifty million, of ten million, of one million, in presence of the known truth that the tax was to be paid by States in which the incomes did not exist?

If it be true, as was asserted by Mr. Choate, that the States of Massachusetts, New York, New Jersey, and Pennsylvania will pay nine-tenths of the income tax under the statute of 1894, is it within the range of conjecture, or the sphere of any man's faith or hope, that the forty other States in the year 1895, or that the poorer States in any time future, destined always to be a majority, will consent to the levy of an income tax under the rule of apportionment? And will any man, whether supporter or opponent of the income tax system, say that the poorer States ought to assume such a burden?

Nor is the case relieved by the suggestion, if the suggestion were well founded, that there was a compromise in the Convention by which rents of lands and gains from personal property were to be counted as the incidents of land, and to be treated as land for the purposes of taxation.

The nation is bound by the Constitution, and not by anything that was said or done in the Convention. The Constitution is silent. It furnishes no direct support to the theory that rents of land are distinguishable from other incomes.

Nor is the theory supported by the Madison Papers. There was one compromise, and one only, touching the subject of taxation, and that compromise was incorporated in the Constitution. The slave States claimed that the slaves should be exempt from the capitation tax. The free States claimed that, as the slaves were producers, they should be subject to a capitation tax, as though they were free. At the end, the scheme of a capitation tax was connected with the basis of representation. The slaves were divided into blocks of five, and for the purpose of assessing a capitation tax, and for the purpose of apportioning representatives among the States, each block of five was to be counted as three free persons. In this arrangement the taxation of land was not touched, nor considered, except that the population of the slave States was reduced in the proportion of two-fifths of the slave population.

The modern suggestion that the rent of lands and the outgrowth of personal property could only be taxed as real estate, was not made by anybody. Neither in the Madison Papers nor in the Federalist is there a hint that such a thought was entertained by anybody.

The quotation by Mr. Choate (p. 18) of a remark made by Mr. Langdon, of New Hampshire, and reproduced in the opinion of the Court, had no application to any feature of the Constitution that is involved in the present discussion.

I do not find in the Madison Papers the remark of Mr. Langdon, as quoted by Mr. Choate in these words: "It will be very hard upon New Hampshire, but we will submit to it for the purpose of carrying this Constitution through."

The remark, as reported by Madison, reads thus (p. 1377) "This would bear unreasonably hard upon New Hampshire, and he must be against it." It was this proposition that was to bear unreasonably hard upon New Hampshire, viz.:

"Mr. Gerry moved to add to article seven, section three, the following clause : That from the first meeting of the Legislature of the United States until a census shall be taken, all moneys for supplying the public treasury by direct taxation shall be raised from the several States, according to the number of their representatives respectively in the first branch."

As early as the 10th of June, 1787, three representatives in Congress had been assigned to New Hampshire, and that when that State was not represented in the Convention.

A motion to reduce its representation to two members had failed. In the debate on the Gerry motion, Mr. Langdon said that he was not present "when New Hampshire was allowed three members. It was more than her share; he did not wish for them." (Madison Papers, p. 1,381.)

Mr. Langdon's protest was not against the scheme of taxation, nor can it be forced, properly, into service in support of the claim that he was engaged in drawing a distinction between incomes that are "the outgrowth of real estate and of personal estate," and other incomes, and agreeing, reluctantly, to a constitution in which the first mentioned were to be levied upon the States in the form of "direct taxes." In truth, he was protesting against the assignment to New Hampshire of three representatives in Congress, when, in his opinion, the State was entitled to two only, upon the basis of population; and for the sufficient reason that the additional member added fifty per cent. to the tax that New Hampshire would be required to pay in case there should be a levy in advance of the census. This was the hardship that was to "bear unreasonably hard upon New Hampshire."

Nothing was said in the Convention, of which any record remains, that touches in the slightest degree the issue raised by Mr. Choate; and had there been pages of record in the line of his contention, his own words would contain a conclusive answer.

"The mere talk of this man or that in the Convention, mere talk of this man or that upon the bench of any court, unless it was a solemn adjudication upon his oath of office and the decision of a case, is of very little weight."

The Constitution is our only guide. That does not furnish any direct support to the new theory of taxation. Turning again to the practical side of this question, is it not apparent that the new theory works the exemption of all incomes derived from real estate and personal estate?

Mr. Choate admits as much when he attempts to show that there will remain adequate sources of revenue, as though a suggestion of that nature could have value in presence of the historical fact that within thirty-five years the resources of the country were taxed to the uttermost, including a levy of five per cent., and an additional levy of five per cent. upon "the outgrowth of real estate and of personal estate," and of all other incomes as well. At the close of an enumeration of the sources of revenue that will remain to the general government after the abstraction for which he contends, Mr. Choate says: "It will leave to the federal government, to be applied by the rule of uniformity, all taxes on transportation of every kind, from the $100,000,000 railroad down to the cart of the licensed vendor."

This, then, is the Constitution, of which four generations of Americans have been boastful, and on which the leaders of thought in other lands have bestowed unmeasured encomiums!

The incomes derived from real estate and from personal estate are eliminated, practically, from the body of taxable property, and we are invited to accept in set-off, and as full satisfaction, the reservation of other means of raising a revenue, including a transportation tax on all articles produced and on all articles consumed by the mass of the people, down to, and including also, the street vendors of peanuts and fruits.

Not so thought Alexander Hamilton. In combating the notion that what was called internal taxation, including incomes, should be reserved to the States, he said of the national government: "Its future necessities admit not of calculation or limitation; and upon the principle more than once adverted to the power of making provision for them as they arise ought to be equally unconfined. I believe it may be regarded as a position, warranted by the history of mankind, that, in the usual progress of things, the necessities of a nation, in every stage of its existence, will be found at least equal to its resources. . . . As the duties of superintending the national defence, and of securing the public peace against foreign or domestic violence, involve a provision for casualties and dangers, to which no possible limits can be assigned, the power of making that provision ought to know no other bounds than the exigencies of the nation and the resources of the community." (Federalist, Nos. XXX. and XXXI.)

The main point of the opinion remains to be considered. It being conceded that land is the subject of direct taxation, and that a land tax must be apportioned among the States upon the basis of population, it is decided that the income of land is an incident of land, and that a tax on the rent is a tax on the land, as the tax on the rent can only be paid from the land. The authority is a quotation from Lord Coke to the effect that a grant in due form of a perpetual right to the rent of land, works, in law, a conveyance of the land from which the rent is derived. "For what," says he, "is the land but the profits thereof ?"

This rule of English law was allied to the system of entail, and it had its origin in that system probably. Of its soundness there is no question. It would not follow, however, even in Great Britain, that an income tax on rents would be treated as a tax on land. However that may be, the rule should be otherwise in the United States. The common law of England extends not beyond the definition of words and phrases known to that law. In many of the States, and with great probability of truth, it may be said that in all the States, the rent of land, when earned, is not distinguishable from other personal property. Upon the death of a landowner his land vests immediately in his heirs-at-law, but rents, earned and uncollected, pass to the executor or administrator. This general policy has its basis in sound reason, and, if it had been accepted, it would have disposed of the contention that for the purposes of taxation the rent of land is not distinguishable from the land itself.

Holmes speaks of a rule of English law touching entailed estates, calls it "early law," and refers it to the times of the Seventh and Eighth Henrys, by which uncollected rents, earned in the lifetime of a tenant, passed with the estate to the new tenant. if such a system existed in this country the quotation from Lord Coke would give some support to the contention.

In this summary view, rather than review, of the opinion of the Court, I have not been influenced by any partiality for the statute of 1894. There ought not to have been occasion for the passage of an income tax act, and it is not improbable that the law will fail, in part, if not altogether, and upon the ground that it is lacking in the quality of uniformity.

The gravity of the decision is in the exemption of rents and incomes of real estate from taxation, except through the system of apportionment, which, in my opinion, has ceased to be a practical and practicable means of raising a revenue.

If the immense incomes derived from real estate are exempt from taxation, there is no moral foundation for the levy of a tax upon professions or pursuits, or upon earnings or upon incomes other than rents. At the end it appears difficult to escape two conclusions—one of law and one of fact:

First: The provision of the Constitution by which direct taxes are apportioned among the States upon the basis of population, is a dead provision, it having become inoperative by the extension of territory and by the unequal distribution of wealth, especially between the old States and the new.

The levy in 1861 of a direct tax of twenty million dollars upon the States was a failure. It was paid by some of the States and neglected by others. The experience under the Confederation was renewed, and after a quarter of a century the States that had paid the tax were reimbursed.

It is not probable that the experiment can be again tried under circumstances more favorable. The power of the general government to levy taxes on, or by, or through the States, has been annihilated by events, and every attempt to transfer additional subjects of taxation to the jurisdiction of that clause is, quoad hoc, an attempt to impair the means by which alone the continuing existence of the national government is made secure.

Second: Inasmuch as the Constitution gives to Congress power "to levy and collect taxes, duties, imposts and excises," and inasmuch as the full and free exercise of that power is the chief, if not the only, means by which Congress can "pay the debts and provide for the common defence and general welfare of the United States," which is the injunction laid upon Congress, it follows that the limiting clauses in the Constitution are to be construed strictly. Nothing is to be excepted out of the powers of Congress beyond what is expressly declared to be so excepted.

Such, manifestly, was the rule of construction adopted by the Court in the case of Hylton, when, of the four members of the Court, two had been members of the Convention of 1787.

GEORGE S. BOUTWELL.

The North American review.
Volume 160, Issue 462
University of Northern Iowa
May 1895

Copyright Family Guardian Fellowship

Last revision: August 14, 2006 08:45 AM
  This private system is NOT subject to monitoring